Francis Fukuyama -- The origins of political order: from prehuman times to the French Revolution ================================================================================================== This book can be viewed as an attempt to help the reader understand major changes and developments in society and political systems, for example: (1) the formation of tribal and family based social organization; (2) the transformation from society based on the status of individual toward a society in which individuals relate to each other based on contracts and agreements; (3) a movement away from a patrilineal society and toward one in which women are able, for example, to own property and in which the tribal and patriarchal structure has been destroyed and in which kinship is no longer the basis for relations and action; and (4) importantly for those of us who believe in democratic forms of government, the transition toward forms of government based on the rule of law and accountability. From status to contract -- An important development is the shift away from society in which social status is ascribed to individuals and where that status controls what the individual does and can do and how that individual relates to others (e.g. her/his occupation, marriage partner, religion, etc.) and toward a society based on contracts, where individuals can contract with each other to form social relationships. According to Fukuyama, relations based on contracts (money, property, and other obligations) have a history that goes back (in England, at least) to the 11th or 12th centuries. These ways of forming social relations and roles and the ability of women to own property, form contracts, and to sue and be sued were important in the break up of and transition from kinship societies. How the Catholic church changed social relations and why -- The Catholic church took a strong stand against marriages between close kin, marriages to the widows of dead relatives, the adoption of children, and divorce. These changes had the effect of making the church rich in land holdings (e.g. widows who ended up with an estate were likely to donate property to the church) and in increasing the holding of property by women (widows specifically). That, in turn, destroyed tribal organization throughout Europe, according to Fukuyama. Fukuyama provides details about how the Catholic Church evolved to become more and more state-like, for example: (1) Beginning with the rediscovered Justinian Code and with fragments of Roman law, legal scholars produced a unified, consistent body of law. (2) Development of a bureaucracy and the concept of office, in particular, the distinction between the office and the office holder produced an early model for a state-like organization. In this bureaucracy, office holders became salaried employees who could be hired and fired based on the quality of their work. Law, in Europe became the motive and the process by which state institutions grew and took shape. The ability to offer and enforce consistent justice and laws across an area became an important enabler of the state. The Magna Carta was not a demand by warlords to be exempted from the law nor a demand for special treatment; it was a demand for consistent, general rules and law and consistent administration of justice. The existence of a separate religious authority (especially one governed by laws) pressured rulers (e.g. kings) to accept the idea that they were not the ultimate source of law nor that they were above the law. Chinese emperors, for example, did *not* learn this. The great political struggles of early modern Europe concerned monarchs who attempted to put themselves above the law, who attempted to make or claimed they could make their own laws, and who claimed that they were not bound by prior law, custom, or religion. The development of a strong legal profession with an interest in interpreting and enforcing and administering the law was also important. The three components of political development that constitute modern politics: (1) the transition out of tribal or kinship-based social organization; (2) the emergence of the rule of law; and (3) accountable government. These led to (1) individual freedom of choice with regard to social and property relationships and (2) political rule limited by transparent and predictable law. And all of these were created by a pre-modern institution, specifically the medieval church. Later chapters of the book examine details concerning how modern states evolved, formed more centralized governments, and made that centralized government accountable, to varying degrees in several recent instances. This story and its variations turns on a struggle between a central power (a monarchy, an elected government, the aristocracy, or the oligarchy) and the third estate (everyone else). Ideas are causes -- The conceptual and mental models that we have (or that our society has) determine the kind of political and social order that we get. Expectations are important; they determine the nature of our political, social, legal, and economic systems. If our society acquires an understanding of the rule of law and comes to expect everyone, including rulers and leaders, to follow the rule of law, then we are likely (or at least, more likely) to obtain a system that is consistent with it. Fukuyama's account of the formation and behavior of political organization in China is especially interesting. He has said, in this book and elsewhere that a highly centralized and autocratic form of government can be especially effective when it is working well, but that he'd rather not experience the bad consequences when it is working badly. It's known in China as "the bad emperor problem", and Fukuyama gives some examples of what goes wrong when the emperor is not accountable and when the emperor either ignores or actively suppresses the bureaucracy in his government. Fukuyama's attitude shows through here, in particular in his description of the horrors inflected by "The evil Empress Wu" and in his claim that the (central) Chinese government has never been under the rule of law in the sense that it has always considered itself above and in control of the law. Having said that, Fukuyama goes on to describe some of the limitations and restrictions that, across time, have limited the power of the central Chinese government and softened its effect on the population. Among these are (1) lack of incentive to deal with such a huge and complex system, population, and nation (land and ownership records were not up to date and, given the lack of a common money, taxes must be collected in kind, so what do you do with all that grain and radishes?); (2) in part because of push back from the population, Chinese emperors often tended to collect just enough taxes to satisfy their needs rather than attempting to maximize the amounts collected; and (3) given the enormous size of the Chinese system, power and tasks must be delegated down multiple levels and across large distances which dilutes and transfers power away from the up most levels of central power. In the case of the Ming dynasty (1368 to 1644) these inabilities to collect taxes eventually led to a failure to pay soldiers and to maintain security and to an eventual collapse. Fukuyama claims that Chinese governments in the past and today fail to satisfy two important conditions of advanced government, specifically the rule of law and accountability. Chinese government has always been and currently is above the law. And, as for accountability, government at all levels is accountable only to the levels above it, leaving the top most level (the emperor earlier and the top level of the Chinese Communist Party currently) accountable to no one. That leaves people with no recourse, when things go wrong or when injustices are committed by local government officials, other than appeal to the top most level or rioting. Fukuyama's vision of history has direction and an end point. It also has an important side effect. The end point has three aspects: (1) a strong state, (2) the rule of law, and (3) accountability. The important side effect is a successful economy (and an improved standard of living). There is an important point to be derived from this: once other (less successful) nations see that a successful economy results from those first three (strong state, rule of law, accountability), they will all want the same. One impressive aspect of Fukuyama's vision is how generic it is. It's obvious that he is a believer in the value of democratic forms of government. But, he is willing to be satisfied with any of a variety of democratic organizations (parliamentary, representative legislature, etc.) as long as the state is reasonably strong; the government is reasonably consistent in following and enforcing a set of laws and does not put itself above that law; and those in the government are accountable to citizens in some way. I suspect that for Fukuyama, it is not even that important whether citizens are able to chose their leaders and government officials, just so long as they can effectively show their displeasure and can "throw the bums out" when they are displeased. But, there are several things wrong, or at least weak, about this picture. For one, you can get a successful political system with a strong state, rule of law, and accountability, and still not have a safe and reliable economic system. We've seen that in the crash of 2008 and are seeing it now in the debt crisis that is afflicting the European Union (in 2011). For more on this see "Culture and prosperity" by John Kay. And, second, this view does not help us deal with the problems that beset a democratic system, such as degeneration into patrimony, capture of legislative and regulatory bodies by powerful and wealthy interests, etc. A third problem is that accountable (democratic) systems seem very weak in their ability to do long range planning and decision making. Fukuyama does not seem to have much in the way of an explanation of this nor suggestions about how it might be alleviated. Perhaps that is an inevitable feature of an explanation that is as broad and general as Fukuyama's. There is one aspect or gap in Fukuyama's explanation that I'd like to see him spend more time on. He mentions several times how precarious the development of a well functioning political system is, specifically one with a strong state, rule of law, and accountability. Theorists in the areas of contingency, chaos, path dependence, and biological evolution all have something to say about this. I'd like to see those theories applied to Fukuyama's. For example, if we had the ability to "rewind and play the tape" over on the development of a specific democratic state, would small differences in initial (earlier) conditions make the development of a functioning state unlikely? Or, is the kind of successful state that Fukuyama describes an attractor, in terms used in chaos theory, so that most states arrive there eventually, though perhaps by different and crooked paths? So, I won't say that Fukuyama has the answers to all our questions, but I do think his way of structuring our thinking about political and societal organizations is interesting and that it certainly provides a platform for asking question about and thinking about how political and social systems form and organize themselves. If you are interested in broad systems theory, it's definitely worth reading. 11/06/2011 .. vim:ft=rst:fo+=a: